1. Kolstad (see 1996a
and 1996b)
recognizes that this argument is only valid as long as it would not be
optimal to negatively emit in the future to correct over-emissions today.
In most of the economic literature on climate change, it is assumed that emissions
cannot be negative, but in principle they can. A biomass energy system with
carbon sequestration and permanent disposal could remove CO2 from
the atmosphere, while at the same time delivering CO2-free energy
carriers (e.g., heat, electricity or hydrogen) to society. This would enhance
the possibilities of climate risk management (see Obersteiner
et al, 2001, and Azar
& Lindgren, 2001).
2. It is thus likely
that the Kyoto protocol (with US participation) can be met without significant
premature retirement of existing capital stock, primarily as a result of the
collapse of Soviet Union and the many built-in flexibility mechanisms. Annex-1
greenhouse gas emissions in 1998 were 6% below the 1990 levels (www.unfccc.de)
and the Kyoto target is an overall 5% reduction, assuming US participation and
no Bonn sinks
3. Ha-Duong et al. used 400 ppmv as a ceiling, i.e., they did not allow any
overshoots. It seems that the fundamental driver for their result is the introduction
of this ceiling. Even a trivially small probability that we are not allowed
to temporarily exceed the 400 ppmv target would force the model to an early
departure from business-as-usual emissions.
4. In the WRE
world these options are already adopted in the baseline scenario. Although this
is not explicit in the original WRE paper, it was a feature of subsequent modeling
efforts developed to support the WRE conclusions. In the baseline scenario developed
by Manne
and Richels (1997), for instance, carbon free technologies capture roughly
40% of the global energy supply by the year 2050 and 70% by the year 2100.
5. IPCC
(1996b) writes that energy efficiency gains of perhaps 10-30 percent
above baseline can be realized at negative to zero net costs. Other authors,
e.g., Ayres
(1994), have pointed to even larger potentials for cost-efficient energy
efficiency improvements, but others are less optimistic. Regardless of one's
assumption about the magnitude of these no regrets options, as well
as equally cost-effective deployment of renewables, all parties agree that this
potential should be tapped as soon as possible.
6. We compare with the
1990 global economy since costs were discounted back to 1990 and expressed in
1990 USD. We chose 1990 in order to facilitate comparison with IPCC estimates,
which are expressed in 1990 USD (see
IPCC, 2001c, Chapter 8).
7. A standard economist
response to this would typically be that by avoiding emissions reductions now,
we would be making people richer in the future, and therefore at least economically
more well situated to accept climate policy initiatives. But not reducing the
emissions means that we can get even more locked into carbon intensive capital,
and perhaps making future generations thus less inclined to abate carbon. Further,
the difference in GDP growth rates between an abatement scenario and a business
as usual scenario is marginal (see Is
the Cost of Stabilizing the Atmosphere Prohibitive?"). Overall,
the relation between willingness to abate carbon seems not to be so strongly
correlated to income. Although India seems less inclined to adopt carbon abatement
policies than Europe, Europe is more willing than USA and Canada who are richer.
8. We compare with the
1990 global economy since costs were discounted back to 1990 and expressed in
1990 USD. We chose 1990 in order to facilitate comparison with IPCC estimates,
which are expressed in 1990 USD (see IPCC,
2001c, Chapter 8).
Go to top
|